::: KNSI : Korea National Strategy Institute :::
::: KNSI : Korea National Strategy Institute :::
       April 18 2024
The G20 Calls Truce on Currency War by Wonhyuk Lim

Wonhyuk Lim Fellow, Korea Development Institute; Fellow, Korea National Strategy Institute


A specter of a lost decade is haunting the United States and China. With its core inflation rate eerily tracking the path of Japan’s in the 1990s, the U.S. faces the risk of falling into sustained disinflation, if not deflation. Persistently high unemployment, combined with the ongoing financial crisis, makes the situation in the U.S. potentially worse than it was in Japan, which managed to maintain employment and social cohesion during what was often called “a happy recession.� China fears that a rapid appreciation of its currency would precipitate mass unemployment and bankruptcies, as Premier Wen Jiabao warned on October 6 at the 6th EU-China Business Summit in Belgium. China is determined not to fall for “Plaza Accord II� and repeat Japan’s mistake—namely, agreeing to a drastic revaluation of its currency, adopting loose monetary policy to buffer the exchange rate shock, turning a blind eye to rapidly rising asset prices, and waiting for firms and financial institutions to grow out of their problems in the wake of the asset price collapse. These fears and anxieties provide the backdrop of the debate on quantitative easing (QE) and the undervaluation of the Chinese renminbi (RMB), two key issues that have framed “the currency war� of the past several weeks.

A two-speed recovery in the increasingly integrated global economy further complicates the picture. While leading emerging economies are currently faced with the risk of overheating, advanced economies, including those with reserve currencies, are concerned about falling back into recession. If leading emerging economies put on the brakes, global aggregate demand would be reduced, with an adverse effect on external demand for advanced economies. On the other hand, if the United States and other reserve-currency countries resort to quantitative easing to fight deflationary pressures, a substantial part of the increased money supply is likely to “leak out� overseas in search of higher yields. As IMF Managing Director Dominique Strauss-Kahn noted in Shanghai on October 18, massive capital flowing into emerging economies could lead to “exchange-rate overshooting, credit booms, asset-price bubbles, and financial instability,� and emerging economies may have to adopt capital controls to moderate the vast flows. To manage the two-speed recovery and promote “strong, sustainable and balanced growth� around the globe, macroeconomic policy coordination is more needed than ever before.

As much as international coordination is critical to recovery, however, it is far more important to get domestic policy right by crafting political consensus. Even in this age of globalization, large economies—whether advanced or emerging—still derive most of their aggregate demand domestically, and a country like the U.S. finds it difficult to narrow its output gap (estimated by the Congressional Budget Office to be 6.3 percent of potential GDP in the second quarter) unless its domestic demand recovers. At the same time, due to the liquidity-trap conditions, loose monetary policy is likely to be largely ineffective in generating additional demand. Under these circumstances, advanced economies with high unemployment and underutilized capacity should adopt a greater fiscal stimulus designed to create jobs and improve infrastructure at home, to crowd in private-sector investment after households and firms repair their balance sheets and recover their confidence. The widely publicized second underwater tunnel connecting New York City and New Jersey may be an example of a productivity-enhancing infrastructure project that would support employment and aggregate demand. In particular, advanced economies should do more to reduce high unemployment, which has such a corrosive effect on consumer confidence and business sentiment. If prolonged, “structural� unemployment will become a self-fulfilling prophesy as workers� skills depreciate. Unfortunately, the U.S. and other advanced economies instituted a rather insufficient fiscal stimulus, even though the bond market was—and is—signaling with extremely low interest rates that they undertake much more aggressive fiscal expansion.

China and other leading emerging economies must deal with exactly the opposite kinds of problems faced by the U.S. and other advanced economies. When the global financial crisis of 2008 broke out, many emerging economies saw their currency values plummet as investors took flight to the so-called safe-haven currencies—with some selling their assets in emerging markets to make up for the losses they suffered in advanced economies. Maintaining capital controls, China put a halt to the appreciation of the RMB, which had risen by 21% over a three-year period since the adoption of a currency basket system in July 2005. With the stabilization of global financial markets and faster recovery in emerging economies than in advanced economies, currency values now have to readjust. Exporters in emerging economies, who have become used to making easy money, may not welcome the prospect of currency revaluation, but emerging economies, facing inflationary rather than deflationary pressures, should take steps to avoid overheating. They should not be afraid of making this adjustment. China suffered no economic catastrophe when the RMB gradually appreciated by 21% from 2005 to 2008. If anything, China became an economic powerhouse over this period. Going back further, Korea used the currency revaluation and wage increase in the late 1980s as an opportunity to upgrade its industrial structure. Similar adjustments, in coordination with major economies, could be mutually beneficial.

The G20 Finance Ministers and Central Bank Governors met in Korea’s ancient capital of Gyeongju on October 22-23 to address these policy challenges, and agreed to “move toward more market determined exchange rate systems that reflect underlying economic fundamentals� and “pursue the full range of policies conducive to reducing excessive imbalances and maintaining current account imbalances at sustainable levels.� They also agreed that persistently large imbalances would warrant “an assessment of their nature and the root causes of impediments to adjustment as part of the Mutual Assessment Process,� in cooperation with the IMF. Although the idea of placing symmetric numerical caps on current account imbalances was floated, the Ministers and Governors failed to produce specific targets, just yet.

This agreement represents a major accomplishment in policy coordination as it enables the G20 to move beyond the narrow focus on the RMB-USD nominal exchange rate and adopt a fair, gradual, and multilateral approach to global imbalances. First, the agreement recognizes that both excessive surpluses and deficits should be fixed, subject to country-specific factors such as natural resource endowment and the asymmetry between reserve-currency and non-reserve-currency countries. In fact, it calls on advanced economies, including those with reserve currencies, to be “vigilant against excess volatility and disorderly movements in exchange rates.� Also, the agreement implicitly acknowledges that while the exchange rate is an important variable, it is not the only variable that affects the savings-investment balance. It explicitly recommends “fiscal, monetary, financial sector, structural, exchange rate and other policies� to deal with imbalances. Second, instead of calling for a big-bang adjustment, the agreement has a medium-term framework to deal with persistently large imbalances, “assessed against indicative guidelines to be agreed.� Third, the agreement recognizes the danger of politicizing global imbalances as a bilateral problem between the U.S. and China and instead defines it as a multilateral issue to be resolved through the Mutual Assessment Process.

Some critics, however, have argued that the agreement lacks teeth and needs specific numerical targets to be effective. Although the behind-the-scene bargaining over numerical targets is likely to be intense, there is a good chance that the G20 will agree to indicative guidelines by the time of the Seoul Summit on November 11-12. As for “teeth,� or enforceability, the fundamental problem is that you can't name and shame great powers because they are, well, shameless and powerful. The effectiveness of the IMF surveillance work and the Mutual Assessment Process will be limited to that extent. However, it will be still useful to have a multilateral mechanism that considers both excessive deficits and surpluses as problems and provides a basis for gradual (not glacial) adjustment. In fact, it is worth noting that one of the major factors that triggered the currency war was the slow adjustment of the RMB in the months following China’s announcement to increase its flexibility on June 19, just before the Toronto G20 Summit. When the RMB appreciated by only 1 percent over the next three months, the economic issue of exchange rate adjustment turned into a much larger problem of trust, and China had to face increasing pressure from other countries to keep its word as another G20 Summit approached. Although great powers always have the option of ignoring other countries, the holding of Summits and Ministerial Meetings at regular intervals ensures that the G20 is far more likely than stand-alone international organizations to follow through on the members� commitments.

The recent G20 agreement doesn't force its members to adopt all the necessary macroeconomic policy or resolve their domestic political problems, but at least it helps to shift the policy focus away from the RMB-USD nominal exchange rate and to larger, more fundamental issues. As such, the agreement qualifies as a step forward. With international coordination taking shape, it is now up to individual nations to craft domestic political consensus to get their policy right.
¡å file download
::: KNSI : Korea National Strategy Institute :::
Copyright 2005 © Korea National Strategy Institute. All Right Reserved.